National Myths and Land
Synopsis
Our myths of 'rugged independence' and egalitarianism, the dream of home ownership and the Cinderella status of local government in Australia have a common root - our access to land across the centuries.This paper examines the connections and explores the concept of The Commons of the UK and the 'Act of Enclosure' of this continent in1788. Our attitude to land and how it is very largely determined by financial considerations is examined. The possibility of the 'hip pocket nerve' being harnessed to encourage a more conscious, respectful and honouring attitude to the of privilege of land ownership is floated - not optimistically!
My paper was prompted by Mungo McCallum's Quarterly Essay No 36 (Black Inc ISSN 1832-0953), informed by James Boyce's, 'Van Dieman's Land' and at least two of Henry Reynolds books and I am pleased to record my appreciation of those stimuli.
Myths
In the Quarterly Essay No 36, Mungo McCallum cites several Australian myths as having been recognised and used by Kevin Rudd, ‘to take them (i.e. us/ the electorate/Aussie battlers/working families) to a country which has never really existed and probably never will, but which is the Australia to which they wish to belong’. Must we share the pessimism that Australia, in reality, will never come up to the hopes and expectations of Australians?
Of the myths, two may usefully be viewed through the prism
of modern Australia’s, attitude to land, real estate, the soil; ‘our
claim to rugged independence’ and ‘the idea of an egalitarian society’.
The Commons and
Independence
In his very well researched history, Van Diemans Land (Black Inc. 2008),
James Boyce relates how the early convicts there felt they had been dumped on
the edge of a vast common. Ironically, many had been sentenced to
transportation because they had been caught using the commons of England in
traditional ways – trapping and snaring game, ways which had been made illegal
under the Game laws and Acts of Enclosure. Boyce’s Introduction contains
many references to the convicts’
acceptance of sharing resources with Aboriginals and each other – land,
water, game – and their adaptability to
go bush, to obtain ‘the essentials of life from the new land’. ‘Van Diemen’s Land was aught but a vast
common’ quotes Boyce, p70, Ref32. Defining his book as ‘an environmental
history’ with the main interest of how the environment changed the settlers,
the early chapters contain many specific references to Tasmania as a common and
its effect on the early settlers, how the free access to the natural resources
led to much entrepreneurial activity
So there was rugged independence in the early days of
settlement and it was engendered by easy access to common land and its natural
resources.
.
Commons are, to this day, very important parts of British
society but the concept of shared use of the land is not a basic feature of
modern mainstream Australia. English Commons have featured strongly in my own
history having been an active Commoner of Ashdown Forest in Sussex (exercised
my ‘Rights of Common’ to wood for fuel, bracken for litter and heather for
thatching etc during the 60s and 70s).
.
The present UK Commons – and they are countless, many not
publicly marked – are the remnants of the countryside still not fully
privatised, remnants left over from the time before ‘ownership’ and formalised
property rights, centuries ago. In the British Isles there were small
communities simply living off the land, simply sharing what resources there
were to provide rudimentary shelter and sustenance; Iron Age stuff and earlier
– as seen on TV’s ‘Time Team’ with Tony Robinson! The present Ashdown Common,
3,000 acres between London and the south coast has a number of villages,
dwellings, cricket pitches and tennis courts, a golf course, wild deer, it
supports Commoner’s sheep and occasional cattle, has many horse trails and
footpaths. It is its present size because the local inhabitants, the commoners
of 1400 AD resisted attempts to enclose the late John of Gaunt’s estate; the
later earl got his way with about half but that was 600 years ago!
Thus the commons of those northern isles supported many
communities which in due time – with many battles, invasions, resistance and
general skulduggery - coalesced into the sort of central government we know
today. But the close association with the land persists in the English psyche
today so that Bill Bryson can write of it as ‘the cherished land’ (UK Magazine,
Resurgence No245). It is crisscrossed by footpaths, bye ways, tow-paths, bridle
paths – many dating from Roman times and earlier – rights of way in use today
and is adorned with marshes, moors, fells, forests, woodland and ponds having
public access rights which are fiercely defended against all comers – sadly not
always successfully. It is this literally ‘grass roots’ history that gives
strength and meaning to Local Government in the United Kingdom today.
In contrast, the Van Diemen’s Land/early Australian
experience of commons was harshly suppressed by Lieutenant Governor George
Arthur in order to supply a servile workforce for the growing number of free
settlers. In chapters 12, ‘Controlling the Convicts’ and 13, ‘Imposing
Dependence’ James Boyce shows how Arthur, with British support and experience,
used every device – secure barracks to prevent ‘fraternising’, informers, a
police force comprising two-thirds serving convicts, meagre carrots and very heavy sticks – to
secure the desired servility. Before
1820 many ex-convicts and some still under sentence had been allowed plots of
land to build crude shelters on, or small land grants for subsistence living
for themselves and families; some had licences to resources to support
rudimentary commercial enterprises. But Boyce quotes, page 156, a John
Henderson complaining that a low-born migrant, ‘soon imbibes such ideas of
liberty, equality and independence’ that renders him totally useless ‘for the
situation of a subordinate’. This was no
way to run a prison nor to support the ambitions and provide the free labour
for the increasing numbers of free-settlers and must be ended. Lt.Gov Arthur
was the man to do this - though there was much resistance and opposition and
total success was never quite achieved.
The myth of ‘rugged independence’? Is it some ancient, primitive dream from
another continent that hardly stood a chance on this one? Or simply a matter of
us living in denial of the harsh realties of how this was broken? Or the
remnant of the opposition to Arthur’s punitive regime, extant still? This is my
hope.
Egalitarian Society – Jack’s as good as his master
According to Boyce, the Van Diemen’s Land experiences would not remain isolated to the island population because the
colony was a very significant part of the early European settlement of this
continent; by 1830 it held 24,000 of the 71,000 non-indigenous population,
60,000 of the 126,000 acres in cultivation, more than half the numbers of sheep
etc. As other parts of the continent were settled, the free-settlers, the land
grantees needed skilled and obedient bush-men, shepherds and stockmen to work
their land. The free settlers may have been skilled at managing accounts, have
the contacts for trading and the necessary capital but without the servant
‘boots on the ground’ no enterprise could succeed. Many Van Diemen’s Land
ex-convicts migrated from their island prison, the oppression, vicious memories
– AND glimpses of independence - to help settle the other colonies,
particularly Victoria.
And maybe this is where the myth of an egalitarian society
started; later it was enshrined legislatively, we are all equal before the law
in theory at least. But on the ground there was, of necessity, a partnership of
the experienced ex-convict, low-born European and the settler, the landowner
usually of the European elite. But equality always was a myth. The concept of
the Commons – worryingly seen in Van Diemans Land to engender ideas of independence and
equality – did not take root and flourish in the new continent. It was reaching
its ‘use by’ date in England and other parts of Britain. In late 18th
and early 19th century in the UK, the Enclosure movement was in full
swing – huge tracts the Commons were being enclosed by the Acts of Enclosure passed by the parliament at Westminster to,
inter alia, improve agricultural production needed by a fast growing, urban
population; people turned off or encouraged to leave their rural subsistence
migrated to towns to become part of the industrial revolution - and they
multiplied.
So it was the
Enclosure movement – or more precisely the idea of absolute property rights
under the Crown - that dominated here not the concept of common land; and that
always meant a population divided as in England. Landowners, the landlords, and the others - those with secure land and those without secure access to land. Henry
Reynolds in his ‘Frontier’ (Allen & Unwin 1996) quotes EJ Hobsbawn, ‘that
what happened to land determined the life and death of most human beings in the
years 1789 to 1848’ and goes on to examine the close parallels between the
conflicts in Europe and the British settlement of Australia; ‘the Aboriginal
experience can be profitably compared to those of the squatters (mostly commoners really; author) on the
shrinking commons, the foresters and men of the fens who struggled to maintain
a traditional economy in opposition to the ever growing commitment to absolute
property rights.’ (Ibid, Conclusion part III)
How did we get here...
White Australia started as a continent of Crown
Land with a recognised, and armed, central authority willing and able to
dispense privileges, particularly land grants and titles, whereas Britain
started, centuries ago, as common land with dispersed and independent communities
evolving through self-managed hamlets, fiefdoms and great estates to towns
providing a high level of sophisticated trading. (G M Trevelyan’s English
Social History is an excellent reference; esp. Chapter XII, Dr Johnson’s
England.) In Australia, the pre-existing, Aboriginal self-managing communities
were practically wiped out and replaced by communities entirely dependent on a
higher, centralised authority – which was in turn, for many years, entirely
dependent on the British on the other side of the world.
This top-down establishment of authority, law ‘n order, is
why Mungo can write, ‘…our history is that of a people who have willingly
acquiesced to authority….have generally been content to do as we are told’ and
speak of ‘our habit of obedience’. It also accounts for the Cinderella status
of Local Government in Australia and, more fundamentally, the absence from the Australian psyche that local communities should
manage their own affairs.
Our rugged independence and idea that we are an egalitarian
society are myths entwined with the history of our relationship with the soil
of Australia.
The Australian Dream
Another myth used by Prime Minister Kevin Rudd quite dramatically, but not
listed by Mungo, is that every Australian can own their own home. Well, maybe it
is a dream that is rapidly becoming a
myth.
As part of the stimulus response to the Financial Crisis of 2008,
Kevin Rudd doubled the Howard Government’s First Home Owners Grant and renamed
it ‘Boost’. This extra money injected into the housing market was welcomed by
many ambitious young couples, the building industry and development lobby. But the millions of dollars fed into the
bottom of the market, has had a huge multiplier effect as existing home owners
have moved up the property ladder by borrowing more against the inflated sale
price of their erstwhile home. In consequence, as we entered 2010 our
national household debt has become
larger than our GDP for the first time ever, mortgage debt being the largest
single element and FHOB has, indeed, been a major boost.
Thus as Prime Minister Rudd collects political points for
making home ownership easier for some and preventing property prices from
falling, overall the price of housing has been increased and affordability
reduced. But, often overlooked, is a
land element to this myth; homes/housing comprise a structure AND the land upon
which it stands. You must be affluent or credit-worthy to get access to the
land before you can build your house. Access to land is not an unqualified
right of citizenship.
The Uncomfortable Whispering
Two of myths listed
by Mungo – ‘rugged independence’ and ‘egalitarian society’ - plus the unlisted ‘home
of ones own dream’ thus drag strong shadows cast by our present
relationship/attitude to land; for want of a better phrase, our lack of
intimacy with the land, the absence from our lives of day to day contact with
the soil in a manner that reminds us how totally dependent we are upon it. There are, of course,
exceptions; individuals and groups throughout the country that regard their land
with respect and reverence through daily contact; I know many in Tasmania. But
when, say, retirement beckons, it is the monetary value of that land that will
determine the choices made; money matters. It is impossible to escape from the
prevailing economic realities. Were these realities fully encapsulated by a Governor of
the Reserve Bank a few months ago when he was reported as declaring, ‘Housing is just something
we consume - like, food, television or cars’? (Dr Guy Debelle,
Asst Governor, Finance, RBA at the Whitlam Institute, Aug 09)
Few of us have the daily use of ancient rights and there is
the uncomfortable truth that we are all living on dubiously 'enclosed' property and that
fortunes and political influence can be gained by trading in this legally
sanctioned contraband. This subconscious unease is what Henry Reynolds has documented
as ‘The Whispering in our Hearts’ Is this the underlying cause of Mungo’s conclusion
that Kevin Rudd using myths - plus commerce-centred politics and mortgages - can
take us to a never never land?
Must we share Mungo’s saddening projection?
The Hip-Pocket Nerve and Land Consciousness
Today’s urban Australian cannot understand, probably has no inkling
even, of what an Aboriginal elder means by, ‘The earth is our mother’ or ‘we
belong to the earth’. A shift in consciousness might have been started if
‘Aboriginal Commons’ had been legislated instead of ‘Native Title’; the latter
has connotations of absolute property rights, the former of ancient rights established in the Dreamtime. We obviously cannot put the clock
back to become commoners and yeoman farmers, still less hunter-gatherers in
order to establish a close and meaningful connection to the soil but is there
some new approach that can raise, in the public consciousness, the fundamental importance
of land, our relationship and access to it?
Mungo correctly observes that ‘the electorate seldom forgets
the hip-pocket nerve entirely’. Maybe if that nerve could be stimulated
regularly in a way to remind land owners and occupiers how privileged they are
to have such access to the essential for life, enjoyment and industry, then
over time - maybe decades - our connection to the land would become more
respectful, conscious and ethical. I am suggesting a shift in the politics of
taxation by the introduction of a Federal Government mandated flat rate land
tax collected by the States (it could used to offset the GST until its
abolition) quarterly through the present Local Rates administration. Each
quarter, those fortunate enough to have unfettered access to a part of
Australia would thus be reminded of that privilege and be prompted to take
stock as to whether it was worth their while or not; if not, there would be
another ready to make profitable and/or enjoyable use of that parcel of land.
The moral case for flat rate land tax is inescapable. If you
want a piece of Australia for your exclusive use, then you pay the rest of us to
keep away. A flat rate with full public disclosure, no exceptions, would see
all pay their proper share of the defence and servicing costs – communications,
labour, environmental – in proportion to the value given to their asset by the community
at large. And the liability could not be dodged, moved to a tax haven or
creatively accounted down to negligible proportions!
There would be many spin-offs for such a levy – including stabilising
the price of land, freeing the economy from some existing tax burdens, reducing
the power of the ‘Jobs, jobs, jobs’ mantra, giving the Reserve Bank more levers
- not just interest rates, etc. But it
is the sub-conscious recognition of the place land must have in our hearts,
life, economy and well-being that would be the greatest and most lasting
benefit of the regular reminder of the privilege of land ownership.
We will continue to be lead….
What are the chances that such might be promulgated and
applied with bi-partisan support?
Very many of our wealthiest list property as their main or
secondary source of wealth – check the BRW 200 List – so they would be opposed.
The development lobby comprising the best and brightest speculators in the land - and the most generous political donors -
are implacably opposed to land tax because it renders holding land idle
unprofitable. The Real Estate ‘industry’ likewise - but with much less
justification – sees land tax as a threat to their profits and, very
significantly, because they are major buyers of advertising space in all the
mainstream media, one can bet on a very bad press for a nation-wide land tax. Additionally,
there are possibly a few amongst the political and bureaucratic elite that
have, as a back-up to their ‘quite-adequate’ pensions, a property asset or
three and they would not look favourably upon anything that impinged on that –
regardless of the public benefit involved.
One can say that the chances of the above suggestion being
taken up are close to Buckley’s. The political response to the Henry Tax Review
will, almost certainly, confirm this. But until we are able to establish a more
honouring, more reverential, relationship with the land, one that recognises
that access to land, holding land is both a right and a privilege, one that
silences ‘that whispering in our hearts’, I believe Mungo’s conclusion will
hold: we will continue to be led ‘to a country which has never really existed
and probably never will, but which is the Australia to which we wish to belong’.
Footnote
Very pertinent to Australia today, the unintended Tasmanian
experiment of 1805 to 1820 – so wonderfully documented by James Boyce –
illuminates the effect of land access/property rights upon a society; easy
access to land and natural resources engenders ideas of independence and
encourages enterprise and personal initiative. The converse propositions are
also true.
These have been well understood and used by elites for at least one
century. In the late-19th century essay on property rights, ‘Archimedes’
attributed to Mark Twain (Google ‘Archimedes Mark Twain’) the author, having
earlier outlined how ‘we’, the top echelons of society, would enjoy untold
wealth and all possible luxury without stooping to get ‘our’ hands dirty or
mixing with the common people, enthuses, ‘What a beautiful arrangement –
ambition urging in the front and fear and want bringing up the rear!’
Countering the challenge that the people would surely wake up to the situation,
he writes, ‘Nothing of the kind, the people are as good as gold …. and I appeal to the facts of today to
bear me witness’. That century-old exhortation can be applied to Australia
today.
Colin Cook,
February 2010, edited December 2016
No comments:
Post a Comment